Intuition

From Harvey and Siddique (2000): “[Risk averse] investors should prefer portfolios that are [positive]-skewed to portfolios that are [negative]-skewed.” The graphic below shows the difference - negative skew entails a long left tail, and a mean below the median:

fig

The following example, with a $1 portfolio and \(u(c_t)=log(c_t)\), supports this claim - assets 1 and 2 have the same expected return, but 1 has left skewed returns and 2 has right skewed returns. The investor gets higher expected utility from asset 2:

fig

Skewness and Expected Returns

Let’s look at the two families of 2\(\times\)3 sorted portfolios using Ken French’s data from 1980-present: Size/Book-to-Market (BM) and Size/Momentum (Prior). For reference, the CRSP value-weighted index had a skewness of -0.7638 over the same period.
The small/high BM portfolio has the highest expected returns - it also has the largest skewness (in absolute value).

fig

fig

The same point is conveyed by histograms (the fitted normal has the same mean and variance as the underlying data). The small/high BM portfolio has a heavy left tail - mass above the blue line to the left of the mean - not present in the big/low BM portfolio:
fig

The relationship is not as strong in the size/momentum portfolios (low prior return = low momentum), but it is still present.

fig

fig

Here, the histogram shows a slightly different picture than the summary statistics - in the small/high prior portfolio, there are a few extreme events (momentum crashes) not present in the big/low prior portfolio. Rare disaster risk could weaken the relationship between skewness and expected returns in these portfolios.

fig

Conclusion

To a first order, the intuition is correct - the more negatively skewed portfolios have higher expected returns.